Direct Link: https://www.captechu.edu/blog/privacy-information-currency
www.CapTechU.edu
By Dr. Jason M. Pittman
Readers of this continuing series on privacy will recall that, in the last installment, I discussed the concept of information parity.
When information is in a state that enables us to exchange it freely,
or when others are able to access the same information as we can,
without restriction, then we can say that parity exists.
I suggested the rising demand for privacy -- a topic which has come
to dominate many discussions about technological innovation,
particularly with regard to digital domains -- is connected to
information parity.
This week, I want to introduce another attribute of information: its potential to be used as currency.
Currency
and parity are related. When information is in a state of non-parity,
then the opportunity exists to use it as currency. It is harder to do
that when exchange of information is unrestricted. Consider academic
databases, for example. They charge a fee, often a steep one, to users
wishing to access a particular academic paper. Parity does not exist in
this case, because access to the information is not unconstrained. If it
were, no one would pay the fee.
What is information as currency then and how does it lead us to ending privacy altogether? Let’s find out!
Currency, in the privacy context, has two potential expressions. The
first expression deals with currency as an object that can be exchanged.
This exchange is volatile and can modulate according to external
pressures. Oddly, the exchange of information defies the apparent nature
of information, in that an information exchange operates under the
premise that one party gains information at the cost of the information
itself (to the other party). Exchange is not an expense to information
though. Rather, exchange is perceived to be at the expense of
exclusivity of knowing information. We’ll come back to this point later.
Secondly, currency is a container for value. The specific value of note in this context is power.
The power associated with information has two additional aspects: power
over information through people and power over people through
information. Yet, information as a currency is not a modern abstraction,
as many proclaim. Certainly, information has been capable of exchange
since the earliest form of oral transmission. Similarly, we can envision
how information has served as a container for power once a method of
fixation become available whether that was stone carvings or Twitter
posts.
As information is exchanged, we perceive negative exchanges more
strongly than positive exchanges. This is to say, the exchange of
information away from our power base creates a more intense mental
imprint than an incoming exchange. As such, the net perception is an
information deficit. Deficits are powerful incentive pathways.
Privacy comes back into the picture because it counteracts such
(negative) information exchanges. More specifically, privacy counteracts
undesired information exchanges. The fact that undesired information
exchanges exist strongly implies that disparity is a dominant
information state. A fantastic example of information as a currency in
this regard is social media.
Social media have done more to instigate the rising demand for
privacy than any other system. Social media have made clear how
information is brokered between entities. More importantly, the power of
information serves as the access fee to these information brokerages.
Yet information is not money. We do not provide a specific quantity
of information to access social media. Thus, social media reinforces the
feeling of information disparity based upon information as currency.
Certainly, the combined ideas of currency exchange and currency as a
container for power fosters a perception of privacy being an equation
balancer in some sense. This is just an illusion, however.
To dispel this illusion, I suggest that privacy must end. We need
more information, and more information sharing free from the bonds of an
illusionary currency. We ought to recognize the real currency of
information - power- and work towards equitable exchanges thereof. Such
exchange presupposes that information is around long enough to be
exchangeable. Thus, tune in next time when I discuss the permanency of
information.
No comments:
Post a Comment